In industrial policy, don’t micro-manage

In industrial policy, don’t micro-manage

The recent case of the BSNL is illustrative. Forced to break away from a confirmed tender to Chinese suppliers for its 4G network, it found that new bidders were 89 per cent more expensive and had no proven track record in producing at scale. Another anomaly is in solar panels, where on the one hand, we want to achieve 100 gigawatt solar capacity but have put tariff barriers on foreign suppliers.

Ajit RanadeUpdated: Monday, November 23, 2020, 12:41 AM IST
article-image

Nokia was once the leader of the world in mobile phone handsets. Its
largest manufacturing plant was located in Sriperumbudur in India as
part of a special economic zone. In a six-year period, it produced more
than 500 million handsets, much of them exported. Nokia employed a
workforce of more than 30,000, including indirect employment, and it
had a big share of women employees. It was indeed the rockstar
example of what it meant to make India a manufacturing hub for the
world. It stood for a high-quality product and the high-quality employment of a global brand, adding to the then brand of ‘Made in India’. But much before ‘Make-in-India’ became a slogan, the Nokia plant was shut down. It has now become a case study in business schools, of the opposite of a
Cinderella story, of how a successful, dream-like story can go kaput.

This is not the place to discuss the demise of the Indian factory in
all its gory details. A part of the blame goes to the excessive zeal shown by
India’s tax authorities, bordering on tax terrorism, and also broken
promises. Blame must also be apportioned to Nokia’s own failure to anticipate the global revolution in smart phones and getting stuck with a large-scale capacity in low-cost feature phones. In hindsight, it can be safely said that much of this woeful story was avoidable and an alternate
glorious future could have been written for Nokia, as well as India’s
prowess in mobile phone manufacturing for the global market.

More importantly, what have we learnt from the Nokia story? Stories of
the excessive zeal of the taxman continue. Despite lowering the corporate
tax rate to East Asian levels and down to 15 per cent for new manufacturing facilities, the mindset is still extractive. India’s tax regime, including the GST system, is still burdensome and inhibits competitiveness. We have been successful in attracting Apple to make its iconic phones in India, so that is something to be celebrated. But as compared to the scale of annual production of a 100 million phones achieved by Nokia, Apple is tiny.

The Apple story was successful thanks to an approach called the ‘production linked incentive scheme’, which gives incentives related to volumes. That has been extended to 13 sectors, including mobile phones, drugs, battery cells, man-made textiles, auto components and solar panels. The total budgeted outgo on incentives is nearly Rs 2 trillion over the next five years. The PLI scheme seems to be supported by protection via import tariffs.


This is an old school economics textbook approach that to attract
investment in the country, you raise tariff walls. Hence, a foreign
player can access India’s vast consumer market only by jumping across
that wall, that is, being forced to invest in India. This is not the
lesson which Nokia or Sriperumbudur taught us. That plant came to India
not by jumping tariff walls, but by being attracted to low-cost labour
and skills, as well as to the ease of doing business in an SEZ. If we promote
domestic production by raising import tariffs, it increases costs for
the domestic buyer significantly. It also acts like an export tax, for
entrepreneurs who are using imported components to re-export their
products.

Unfortunately, India reversed its two-and-a-half-decade old
progress in tariff reduction in 2018. Since then, India’s average
import tariff on industrial products has gone up from 13 per cent to 18
per cent and has been applied to nearly one-third to one-half of all
10,000 odd product lines. Remember, high import duties increase
domestic costs and are a de facto export tax as well. Additionally,
the PLI scheme’s approach is to pick winners and champions. In some
sectors, this makes sense.

For instance, India’s import dependence on China for advanced pharmaceutical intermediates is 68 per cent and that
needs to go down. It is also a strategic sector, since it is in
healthcare. But India’s status as a leading bulk drugs exporter to the
west is also dependent on import of APIs from China. So, while PLI for
APIs is good, it will take some time to wean away from China
dependence. But in general, the government cannot, and should not be
in the business of choosing winners and champions, and least of all,
future trends in technology. Imagine if the government had a PLI
scheme for Nokia to produce low cost 2G phones in very large
quantities, it would have been stuck to paying for an obsolete
technology and if it abruptly discontinued it, then it would have
been guilty of breaking a sovereign promise.

Such are the perils of incentivising production in fast technology industrial fields. Another hazard of PLI is that the government may specify too many details and try to micro-manage. This may be due to bureaucratic approach, or excessive caution in preventing abuse of government subsidies. One example of this overkill is that the bid document for the auto sector for those who wish to apply for PLIs is 187 pages long! Imagine the compliance cost. No wonder that so far, not many big players have stepped in, either for auto or for pharma. Thus, industrial policy which is too intrusive, too prescriptive, too keen to pick and choose winners, and
far too based on protectionism is bound to get tangled and not
succeed.

The recent case of the BSNL is illustrative. Forced to break away
from a confirmed tender to Chinese suppliers for its 4G network, it
found that the new bidders were 89 per cent more expensive and had no proven track record in producing at scale. Another anomaly is in solar
panels, where on the one hand, we want to achieve 100 gigawatt solar
capacity but have put tariff barriers on foreign suppliers. This will
increase the cost of domestic production of solar power. It is
inevitable that with too many conditions, India’s industrial policy will
become incoherent and inconsistent. The best approach is that which
gives private and foreign investors stability, predictability and continuity in a broad policy stance. Leave out the micro specifications if you want to succeed.

The writer is an economist and Senior Fellow, Takshashila Institution

The Billion Press

RECENT STORIES

Dream Girl Missing In Action In Mathura

Dream Girl Missing In Action In Mathura

Analysis: Breaching Boundaries, Confident PM Aims To Revive Listless Cadres

Analysis: Breaching Boundaries, Confident PM Aims To Revive Listless Cadres

Editorial: The PM Crosses The Limit

Editorial: The PM Crosses The Limit

Editorial: Surat Steals The Show

Editorial: Surat Steals The Show

Analysis: Why Does The Fed Action Matter To All Countries?

Analysis: Why Does The Fed Action Matter To All Countries?